Contents of spoon-archives/aut-op-sy.archive/papers/harvie.alienation
ALIENATION, CLASS AND ENCLOSURE IN UK UNIVERSITIES
David Harvie
February 1997
Thanks to Alfredo Saad-Filho, whose comments have
improved the argument and its presentation in this paper.
Introduction
The working conditions of many academics in UK
universities have deteriorated sharply over the past two
decades or so, even if =91for many the academic labour
process remains in its core activities [of teaching,
research, scholarship, counselling and administration]
remarkably constant=92 in terms of the type or work (Miller
1991: 111). There have been dramatic and drastic changes
in higher education: university budgets, together with
funding in general, e.g., student grants, have been cut,
student numbers have increased and assessment of both
teaching and research has been introduced with a
vengence. There is no need to spell out the consequent
effect on academic workloads. Academics have been
squeezed by pressure from three sources. First, there is
an increased number of students: a system designed to
impart learning to a small elite, also providing an
element of pastoral care, is now struggling to adjust to
mass education. Second, related to the burgeoning student
population, and despite the employment of dedicated
administrators in many departments, is a growing burden
of administration. Third, there is research, the focus of
this Polemic.
My argument in a nutshell is that academic researchers in
U.K. universities are in the midst of a revolution, which
is somewhat akin to the transition from feudalism to
capitalism. If successfully completed, this revolution
will have disastrous consequences for the majority of
research academics=92 freedom and job security. As part of
this revolution we are seeing a number of related
processes:
the reduction of essentially unmeasureable research use-
values to quantifiable =91research value=92;
primitive accumulation and enclosure of academic
=91commons=92;
the emergence of two classes of academic, a research
capitalist class and a research proletariat, with the
class of research capitalists starting to challenge
heads of department (=91lords of the manor=92) in terms of
the economic and political power they wield within
higher education.
Related to these processes are increasing specialisation
and division of academic labour.
Higher education and capital; universities as
intellectual commons
The integration of higher education into the capitalist
economy has long been recognised by Marxists. Theorists
of the =91social factory=92 such as Mario Tronti argued that,
far from being in some sense outside of capitalist social
relations, schools and universities=92 role as shapers of
young workers, as (re)creators of labour-power, made them
central to the process of value- and surplus value-
creation. There is also a long history of links between
business and universities, with an equally long history
of people organising struggles against these links and
the subsumption of the interests of both university
students and staff to those of capital accumulation. An
early example of this is the subject of Warwick
University Ltd (Thompson 1970); more recent ones, in the
Canadian and US contexts, respectively, are discussed in
Buckbinder and Newson (1988) and Ovetz (1996).
Interesting in this context is the recent explicit
recognition by the present government that much education
policy, and in particular, government stipulations on
curricula in schools and course content in higher and
further education, will be guided by the expressed needs
of =91business=92. Recently, some so-called =91failing=92 schools
in the US and the UK have even been taken over by the
corporate sector. [ref. the economist] The past couple of
decades have seen closer links between universities and
private sector companies as academics have sought money
to make up for falling state funding. Slaughter and
Leslie define =91institutional and professorial market or
market-like efforts to secure external moneys=92 as
=91academic capitalism=92, in their book of the same title
(1997: 8). In this Polemic, however, this term conveys a
different meaning.
A number of other changes and trends have been identified
and theorised. Several authors, for example, have
examined the rise of managerialism in higher education
(refs) and the proletarianisation of academics (refs).
Wilmott (1995) argues that there have been major
developments in the past 10 or so years which have
=91significantly eroded the protection from pressures to
render [academics=92] work more commensurable with the
commodity form of value=92 (p. 995)
Miller (1995) discusses in detail the changes in
universities in terms of a number of agencies and
relationships. These include =91the state and universities=92
and =91the economy and universities=92 and =91university
management and academics=92. At each =91level=92 there are
forces acting to pressurise academics. I have no argument
with Miller=92s account of these shifts and forces;
however, they tell only part of the story. The dynamic
forces described by Miller are all external to academics:
in addition, there are forces which are internal to the
body of academics. Within universities themselves
=91management=92 (or =91the university=92) is counterposed to
=91academics=92. =91Managment=92 may well include many (mostly
senior) academics: these individuals gain management
status through appointment or election to a governing
body (e.g., senate or council) or position (e.g., head of
department). Academics, as academics, though Miller is
well aware that different individuals and groups are
being affected in different ways by current changes, are
seen as a universal body.
However, despite this integration of education
institutions within the capitalist economy, the
relationship until recently has largely been external. By
this I mean simply that the internal organisation of
universities, and other research institutions, has not
been capitalistic. By and large, they have not been
realms within which anything like the law of value has
operated. Despite its =91ivory tower=92 moniker, H.E. has not
been any bastion of =91liberty, equality and solidarity=92,
though many academics have enjoyed far better conditions
than many other workers. Rather, universities have
historically been organised along lines which in some
ways have been far more akin to feudalism and/or an
artisan-centred economy.
Consider the position of the British university academic
two decades ago, say. This person employed as a Lecturer
or Senior Lecturer enjoyed almost complete job security.
In return, this academic was required to devote a fairly
smallish proportion of their time to teaching and
administrative duties. A level of research activity was
also expected, depending upon the particular institution,
but monitoring of this was minimal: the contracted
obligation was to engage in reasearch or other =91scholarly
activity=92, rather than to produce a research output.
Although research output of high quantity and quality
would almost certainly be rewarded financially through
promotion, to a Readership or Chair, say, and in terms of
academic prestige, even a university lecturer who
published nothing could expect to enjoy a high and, for
the most part, rising income, which placed them amongst
Britain=92s highest earners, on a par with senior civil
servants and top police officers.
This situation of material security allowed research
activity to be organised in a particular way. In some
respects academics were akin to artisans, in others
perhaps to serfs. Most worked alone and the products of
their labour =97 research =97 formed a collection of use-
values.1 Academics did research because they wanted to
and, with few external pressures, published only if they
thought they had some ideas or results worth publishing.
Within this system, the requirements for researh =97
library facilities, an office, an intellectually
stimulating environment and, probably most importantly,
time =97 were available to all academics who wished to make
use of them: for employed academics these resources were
intellectual commons; the =91tithe=92 that they paid was the
set proportion of their time which they had to devote to
teaching and administrative duties.2 For students, though
not the focus of this Polemic, the combination of less
pressured academics, well-stocked libraries, the grant
system and few graduation employment worries meant that
for them too, universities were intellectual commons.
Within this system, academics were usually answerable to
their heads of department. With nearly all academics
enjoying tenure, the departmental head=92s position was
more akin to that of the feudal lord: s/he could try and
discipline the =91lazy=92 lecturer, using moral pressure or a
few extra administrative or teaching duties, but sacking
them was usually not an option. Nevertheless, a common
opinion is that heads of department were much more
powerful, and less accountable, in the past, and in some
cases had the power to destroy someone=92s career. From the
lecturer=92s perspective, they were of course, unlike the
feudal serf, free to move if they chose. But, with fewer
pressures to constantly improve research performance, and
seek promotion, there was simply less reason to do so.
At a mostly subjective level =91good=92 research was
distinguished from =91bad=92; there were generally-accepted
notions of =91good=92 journals, departments and individuals,
etc., but these things were not quantified, nor as
mentioned above was there a close correlation between
research quantity and =91quality=92 and material reward.
Moreover, academics passed through a period of
apprenticeship, completing a Ph.D. or some other research
project, under the guidance of an established academic,
the =91Master=92, a point made in passing by Marglin (1974).
An important characteristic of this apprentice system was
that the project was the student=92s own =97 a prospective
D.Phil. candidate would usually write their own proposal,
obtain their own funding from an H.E. institution or
funding body, and choose (or negotiate) their own
supervisor(s). Once the apprenticeship was satisfactorily
completed, young academics could fairly easily move into
a lecturing position, gaining control of sufficient
resources-the researcher=92s =91commons=92: sufficient free
time, money, use of a library and possibly a computer-to
continue their own research. Thus the apprentice became
journeyman.
Neoliberalism and the imposition of the law of value in
H.E.
The attempt to impose the law of value in academia can be
seen as being part of the economy-wide and global project
of neo-liberalism. It is fundamentally concerned with
strengthening the link between money and work, in this
case research work. In academia, this project has several
elements. Perhaps the most fundamental is the
quantification or valorisation of research, through which
researchers are also becoming increasingly alienated from
the product of their labour. If there is to be a strong
link between money and work in universities then it must
be possible to quantify academic research work. In the
UK, this is happening through research selectivity
exercises, the universal (across all disciplines), four-
yearly (at present) Research Assessment Exercise (RAE).
Standards of measurement vary. In some disciplines
authorship of books is the principal unit. In others,
such as economics, refereed journal articles are
preferred, with journals ranked such that a publication
in one may be =91worth=92 much more than a publication in
another. The point is that research output is no longer
simply a use-value; it now has RAE-value which, as I go
to argue, has an similar purpose within academia to
exchange-value or value, in the normal Marxist sense, in
the wider economy. Standardisation and method of
measurement are still incompletely worked out: the
Chairman and Deputy Chairman of the Business and
Management RAE Panel for the 1996 Exercise discuss some
of these issues in an article in Cooper and Otley (1998).
Miller (1995) discusses some of the external changes to
funding and so on which have been driving the process.
>From 1974 block grants from central government fell from
making up 77% of total university income to only 55% in
1987. In 1986 the basis for funding changed: funding for
research is now dependent upon a department=92s research
reputation and the amount of awards it has been granted
from independent research grant-awarding bodies. In 1986,
the year of the first research assessment exercise, the
proportion of research funds allocated on its basics was
10%. This rose to 30% in 1989 and 100% in 1992 (Miller
1995: 16 and 144). Moreover, the 1991 White Paper Higher
Education: A New Framework and subsequent 1992 Act
provisioned increased competition and selectivity in
research funding (Miller 1995: 17-18).
Linked to the funding question is that of labour
contracts. The Education Reform Act of 1988 =91appointed
comminssioners to ensure that university statutes make
provision for the dismissal of staff on the grounds of
redundancy - that is, when the institution ceases to
carry on an activity, teaching or research, for which a
person was appointed=92 (Miller 1995: 17). And Miller
suggests the national pay dispute of 1988-9, with its
imposed settlement of May 1989, was significant in that
it paved the way for both performance-related pay and
market-related pay at the discretion of local university
management (Miller 1995: 134). In 1993, at Aston
University, for example, control of use of discretionary
money passed to departments with the development of the
=91trading company model=92, which designated academic,
administrative and service-providing departments as cost
centres (Miller 1995: 145-147).
There are two points which should be noted about research
and its RAE-value. Firstly, (RAE-)valorisation is not
something which occurs after the research has been
produced. Rather, RAE-valorisation has become an organic
part of the production process itself. Research is
produced for the RAE, research projects and the papers
they will most likely yield are conceived, planned and
executed always with at least one eye on the next RAE.
Given the rewards and costs involved, this is almost
inevitable.
Secondly, the RAE-value of research is not determined by
the actual, or concrete, research labour time (quantity
of work) taken to produce it. Instead the RAE-value of a
journal article, say, is determined by some notion of
=91socially necessary=92 research labour time, how long it
would take for the =91average=92 academic to produce. These
norms here are as yet incompletely worked out, which is
not surprising given that there have been only four
research selectivity/assessment exercises to date (in
1986, 1989, 1992 and 1996) and given the difficulties
from the assossors=92 point of view. (For example, the
=91research cycle=92 is uneven: long years without
publications may lead to a large number of closely
related papers.) In 1996, =91economists=92, i.e., those
researchers working in economics departments or assessed
by a/the panel of economists, were judged by their four
=91best=92 journal articles over the previous four years.
Thus, we can interpret this as meaning that if one wants
to be considered a =91good=92 economist, one must publish (at
least) one article, in a =91good=92 journal, every year; or
that, the socially necessary research labour time for the
production of a =91good=92 article is tending towards one
year. Of course, the four-yearly assessment is rather
unwieldy, generating both a flurry of =91transfer activity=92
(=91top=92 academics moving to departments wishing to improve
their rating and willing to pay) prior to the research
submission deadline and a vast workload for the
assessors. According to the more informed rumours,
research selectivity therefore appears to be moving in
the direction towards continuous assessment. Presumably
the ideal scenario (from the assessors=92 perspective)
would be one in which researchers and their research are
assessed at the time of publication.
At present, RAE results are published in the form of a
rating, ranging from =915*=92 for the most research-
productive departments, down to =911=92. More disaggregated
figures, rating individual research groups within a
department are also made available, to that department.
It is thus possible to rate individual academics in the
same way. As a result of therefore of this process of RAE-
valorisation it is increasingly possible to measure the
work of a labour economist, say, against that of a growth-
cycle theorist, or possibly even an astrophysicist or a
specialist in renaissance Italian literature (or
whatever).
Research selectivity, and the process I am describing as
RAE-valorisation, is having or is likely to have a number
of effects.
1. Perfomance-related pay. Of course, to some extent,
academics=92 pay is already dependent upon their individual
research performance. Promotion (which carries enhance
pay, of course) depends upon an academic=92s research
record to a far greater extent than their ability in
either of their other two =91core=92 activities of teaching
and administration. The same can be said of the award of
discretionary points in the salary scale. With the RAE
inducing far more =91transfer activity=92 between academic
departments it is likely we will see a closer link
between research performance and remuneration. Put
simply, many departments in search of a high RAE research
rating are willing to offer higher salaries to attract
academics with impressive CVs; in turn these same
academics=92 current employers must be prepared to offer
them comparative rewards in order to keep them.
One current proposals is the introduction of profit
related pay schemes which would first require academics
to accept a notional pay cut. The removed slice would go
into a =91profit pool=92, which would then be redistributed.
Proponents argue the end result would be increased pay,
but this would be dependant upon the university achieving
a =91surplus=92. This proposal would also involve a change in
contracts which would undermine national collective
bargaining. The introduction of differentials between
universities would also pave the way for wage
differentials within universities. (see AUT Update no.
35)
2. Influence of the type of research done. Harley and Lee
(1998) suggest the RAE, in economics at least, is forcing
researchers towards the orthodox, neoclassical paradigm.
Their argument is simply that the orthodox journals are
more prestigious and therefore articles published in
those journals are =91worth more=92 than those published in
non-mainstream alternatives. They present evidence to
show that many economics departments actively encourage
applicants with mainstream-journal publications when they
have job vacancies. Academic economists with insecure job
tenure are thus under pressure to do research within the
orthodoxy. More generally, the pressure on all academics,
whatever their discipline, to produce research output, as
opposed to simply being engaged in research, must mean
there is an incentive to undertake =91safe=92 research
projects, that is, those which are more likely to yield
publishable, if not Earth-shattering, results. Moreover,
with assessement every four years, the incentive must be
to not to engage in lengthy research projects. You wonder
what would have become of the British mathematician
Andrew Wiles, based at Princeton University, who in 1994
solved the 350 year old Fermat=92s Last Theorem, a
fantastic achievement. Wiles spent seven years working on
the problem, with no certainty of success, and during
that time did little other research. Or of Sraffa
3. Alienation. There are several aspects to alienation.
With research selectivity academics are under pressure to
maximise the RAE-value of their research. At the limit,
this will be the only consideration when submitting and
publishing work. In all other respects the destination of
their research product will be a matter of indifference:
the researcher exchanges their product for RAE-value and
through this mechanism of exchange becomes alienated from
this product. At editors of Capital and Class, we have
certainly noticed a trend in this direction over the past
few years. Where once Capital and Class would have been
first-choice, many authors are more likely to initially
submit articles to =91higher-ranking=92 journals =97 usually
journals which reach a far smaller socialist/communist
readership. Of course, changes in an author=92s =91target=92
journal will probably imply changes in their paper=92s
content, too. Socialist/communist research loses out.
Again, at the limit, reseach done purely to generate RAE-
value does not satisfy the human need to create
(understanding and knowledge in the case of academics).
Such research work becomes a chore imposed by others and
is undertaken merely to satisfy needs external to the
activity itself.
Research capitalists and proletarians; publications as
capital; the accumulation of academic capital;
enclosures and primitive accumulation
Alienation in a stricter sense involves not only
alienating one=92s product but one=92s labour-power as well =97
the selling of one=92s labour-power. Here both labour-power
and the product of the resulting labour belong to the
employer. If we equate =91ownership=92 with named authorship
of research papers, it is clear this already happens in
academia, whenever a research =91assistant=92 or =91fellow=92 is
employed.
What matters in academia are publications. What matters
most are single- or first-author articles in a =91good=92
refereed journal, published recently such that they
=91count=92 towards the next RAE. Having (=91owning=92) such
publications provides one with greater access to the
resources necessary to pursue further research, research
=91means of production=92, which are made available through
obtaining an academic job and/or research grant. The
research worker, as a rule, =91possesses=92 few such
publications and therefore has an extremely limited
access to these =91means of production=92. The research
worker, in short, owns nothing but their ability to do
research and is therefore forced to seek employment as a
research assistant.3 On the other hand, the =91research
capitalist=92 is someone with many publications to their
name. Such publications mean that this person is not only
likely to be able to obtain a senior academic job, they
are also likely to be successful in applications for
larger research grants. Large research grants allow one
or more research assistants (or research fellows) to be
employed. The crucial point here is that these
researchers are working on someone else=92s project. Of
course research managers do not have complete control
over the production process nor can they appropriate all
that is produced, but again this is to miss the point: in
any work-place, the employer=92s control of the work
process and the product is limited to a greater or less
extent and is subject to struggle. Directors of research
projects are named authors on resulting papers.
(Arrangements concerning authorship vary, of course. In
some projects the research assistants will be first-
author; in others their name will appear only in the
acknowledgements.) In effect research directors are
setting in motion research labour-power. It is the
=91ownership=92 (authorship) of publications which confers
this power on them and the result, if the project(s) is
successful, is the =91accumulation=92 of more RAE-value
(publications). The situation for the research assistant
at the end of a research project varies. Sometimes, they
will have gained authorship of a sufficient number of
publications, as part of the project, to be a position to
obtain a lecturing job, say, which allows them greater
freedom, though this might be only as a result of
struggling to pursue their own projects at the same time
as their research assistant research. In other cases, the
research project will end leaving them in the same
position as at the beginning =97 owning insufficient
publications to do anything but obtain another research
assistant position.
It is increasingly common for some academics to
simultaneously be director of several projects. Such an
individual may well approach the extreme of a =91pure=92
research capitalist. This person is able to employ a
large number of research workers, who not only do the
bulk of the research work, but whose job also includes
writing new research proposals, under the direction of
the research capitalist, to fund the next project and
most likely to secure their own future employment. In
such a way the research capitalist is able to accumulate
a vast number of publications and control huge resources.
With their extensive CV this person is likely to gain
widespread authority within their discipline, through
editorship of key journals or positions on funding
councils, say and is thus able to have disproportionate
influence over its future direction. With their control
of significant monetary resources, they will wield
considerable power within their own department and
university, and therefore challenging the established
hierarchy of heads of departments, deans and so on. (Of
course, research capitalists may be heads of department,
but this doesn=92t affect the argument =97 some feudal lords
became successful capitalists.)
If their secure income, limited teaching and
administrative committments and rich library resources
were the academic-of-old=92s intellectual commons, then the
current ongoing process in UK HE is one of enclosures and
primitive accumulation. This process is uneven, of
course. At the most basic level of material security, one
third of UK academics are now employed on fixed-term
contracts (AUT ??). In a large number of departments,
even for those academics with tenure, access to the
=91intellectual commons=92 is being squeezed, by the pincers
of rising student numbers and falling budgets for
library, computing, conference, etc. facilities. The
typical academic in such a department, if they wish to
engage in a serious research project, is likely to be
forced to depend upon a series of discretionary grants in
order to =91buy out=92 teaching, purchase a adequate
computer, etc. In those =91top=92 departments with better
=91permanent=92 research facilities, the long-term
maintenence of these facilities is likely to depend upon
=91good=92 collective research performance and researchers in
these departments will be under considerable pressure
(both formal and informal) to =91pull their weight=92.
Specialization and division of labour
A by-product of this research-bourgeois revolution is to
accelerate the process of specialisation and division of
research labour. This is further contributing to academic
alienation, on at least two levels.
First, academic disciplines (and sub-disciplines and so
on) are becoming more specialised and there is an
exponential growth in new specialisms. With this growth
it becomes more difficult for any single researcher,
struggling to keep up with advances in their own and
related specialisms, to step back to view their work in a
broader perspective. The new pressures to produce =91good=92,
i.e., publishable, research at the =91cutting edges=92 mean
practicing researchers have even less time in which to
pursue the goal of wider intellectual understanding. In
effect researcher workers are becoming increasingly
alienated from society=92s body of knowledge, which they
have helped produce and continue to expand. And as
researchers become alienated from societal knowledge,
this leaves others with more political and economic power
free to interpret and therefore appropriate for their own
ends this knowledge.
Second, at the level of individual research projects, an
increasing proportion of research is collaborative,
whether or not such research is done under the direction
of a research capitalist or is more self-managed. These
research groups range in size from just a couple of
people to teams of perhaps one or two dozen people
(common in applied physical science). In such projects,
each team member specializes in a different aspect of the
research, and may have limited or no involvement in the
other aspects. As a result, they may not fully understand
the final results. It now seems common for the presenter
of a (multi-authored) paper in an applied economics
seminar, say, to prohibit questions on the econometrics
on the grounds that this was carried out by (one of)
their co-author(s) and they do not really understand it!
Also common is the applied econometrician or statistician
who analyses data sets with only a very hazy
understanding of either the conditions under which the
data was collected or the theoretical framework driving
the quantitative questions they are supposed to be
answering. In these cases it must be said that these
researchers have become alienated from the knowledge they
are producing. With a goal of =91increased productivity=92
such a division of labour may be necessary, but with
proficiency in any one element of a research project=92s
work requiring years of practice, some degree of such
alienation is perhaps inevitable.
This phenomenon has obvious implications, which I do not
need to spell out here, for the balance of power between
employed research worker, on the one hand, and the
research project director (i.e., the research
capitalist), on the other.
The process of primitive accumulation and capitalist
revolution I am attempting to describe has reached
different stages in different academic disciplines.
Broadly speaking, at the risk of being charged with
technological determinism, this appears to depend upon
the extent of the material needs of research in that
discipline. Another factor is the degree to which
=91outputs=92 can be separated from =91inputs=92. In arts
subjects and many social sciences research and production
are very personal; output is inseparable from (personal)
input. The process is most advanced in the physical
sciences, in which research activity demands a large
amount of expensive equipment. It is common for research
in subjects like astrophysics and chemistry to be carried
out by teams of a dozen or more people, under the
direction of a single senior researcher. It seems to be
least advanced in the arts where, on the whole, very
little equipment is required to do research. The social
sciences and humanities lie somewhere in-between.
Collaborative research does not necessarily mean research
undertaken by research workers directed by a research
capitalist; nor does it necessarily that the members of a
research team will be alienated from the research
=91product=92. It may instead indicate greater cooperation
amongst free producers. However, the extent to which
collaborative research has become more widespread over
the past few decades, across a range of disciplines is
interesting and suggests my thesis cannot be immediately
rejected. The figures plots the mean number of authors
per article published by seven differents journals,
including Capital and Class, over the past four decades.
In all cases there is a clear trend towards more
collaborative work.
FIGURES 1A AND 1B HERE
The poverty of opposition
The process I have been describing is marked by the
limited extent of most critiques and opposition. The
fundamental purpose of the process is to control academic
workers through the imposition of a strong link between
money and work. The process also influences the nature
and content of academic research. There is a possibility
that, eventually, in order to get the rewards (RAE-value,
funding, etc.) all problems to be tackled must be
sanctioned as such by the =91establishment=92=97well-
established researchers, funding agencies, Parliament,
corporations. Academics end up being cajoled into solving
problems for the establishment=97capital=92s problems! This
is already very clear in those fields more closely
affected by military research. RAE-valorisation should be
opposed in its totality.
Unfortunately most opposition to date seems to have
focused on attempting to modify the way in which research
assessment is implemented. One tendency is to argue for
different scales on which to judge and measure differing
research output. Another is concerned with the effect on
non-orthodox research within the social sciences, for
example. This tendency is keen to emphasise that Marxist
or radical research shouldn=92t be discriminated against.
But by doing so, the point that this research is still
being reduced to pure RAE-value and that work is still
being imposed is implicitly conceded: Marxism thereby
becomes a potentially =91profitable=92 niche market.4
Perhaps the idea of a research strike, along the lines of
the Art Strike 1990=961993, proposed by the PRAXIS group in
1985 is worth debating. For the art strike, the
propaganda and discussion in the period leading up to its
proposed start were of more importance than the strike
itself, which was probably never a serious proposition.
(See Home 1989 and Here and Now 1990).
Conclusion =97 social antagonism and class in academia
My argument perhaps becomes still clearer if we
understand class, not as a defined group of people, but
rather as being based primarily on the antagonism in the
way human social practice is organised. Although =91the
polar nature of the antagonism is reflected in a
polarisation of the two classes, the antagonism is prior
to, not subsequent to, the classses: classes are
constituted through the antagonism=92 (Holloway 1998:
183=964). Holloway suggests social antagonism
is a conflict between creative social practice and
its negation, or, in other words, between humanity
and its negation, between the transcending of limits
(creation) and the imposition of limits
(definition). The conflict does not take place after
subordination has been established, after the
fetishised forms of social relations have been
constituted: rather it is a conflict about the
subordination of social practice, about the
fetishisation of social relations (1998: 183).
Research, the pursuit of knowledge and understanding, in
any field you care to think of, is creative human
activity. For many =91professional=92 thinkers there is (or
was) no real distinction between work and leisure.
Although in the past there have been barriers between
=91disciplines=92, these were far less clear cut than they
were today. Such creativity is being defined to death.
Within academic research there seem to be limits
whichever way you turn: what to read, how to think, how
to write, how many words to write, who to cite (creative
work turned against creators), where to publish and so on
and so on and now, with =91research assessment=92, how many
articles to publish. Of course, there are always people
attempting to overcome these limits. There are always
people attempting to transcend discipline barriers,
despite the huge costs often involved, in terms of
reading new literatures, putting one=92s position within
one=92s =91own=92 discipline at risk, and so on. Moreover, many
transcending =91seminal=92 papers, which cut across
=91(sub)disciplines=92 end up imposing limits as a new
=91(sub)discipline=92.
This antagonism in academia, between creativity and its
limitation, is not especially new. What is new is the
power which =91research assessment=92 promises/threatens to
measure and define. In turn measurement and definition
offers capital greater opportunities to limit and control
intellectual creativity within universities through
enclosure of =91intellectual commons=92. Researchers thus
become alienated from their creative output. What is also
new is the extent to which =91research assessment=92, and its
related research-funding arrangements, offers a small
minority of academics the opportunity to participate
directly in and benefit from the exploitation and
appropriation of the research work, the creativity, of
others, the majority of us. It is in this way that
antagonism in academia is now constituting two new
classes within academia.
References
AUT (1996) Update, no. 35, 3 June, London: AUT.
Harley, S. and F.S. Lee (1997) =91Research Selectivity,
Managerialism, and the Academic Labour Process: The
Future of Nonmainstream Economics in U.K.
Universities=92, Human Relations, vol.50, no. 11, 1426-
1460.
Here and Now (1990) =91Art/Anti-Art Supplement=92 to issue
10.
Holloway, J. (1998) =91Dignity=92s Revolt=92, in J. Holloway
and Elo=EDna Pel=E1ez (eds) Zapatista! Reinventing
Revolution in Mexico, London and Sterling, VA: Pluto
Press, 159=96198.
Home, S. (1989) editor Art Strike Handbook, London.
Lee, F.S. and S. Harley (1998) =91Economics Divided: The
Limitations of Peer Review in a Paradigm-Bound Social
Science=92, Capital and Class, 66 (Autumn), pages.
Marglin, S. (1974) =91What do bosses do? The Origins and
Functions of Hierarchy in Capitalist Production=92
Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 6, Summer.
Also in Gorz, A., editor, The Division of Labour: The
Labour Process and Class Struggle in Modern
Capitalism. Brighton: Harvester, 1976.
Miller, H. (1991) =91Academics and their Labour Process=92 in
C. Smith, D. Knights and H. Willmott (eds.) White-
Collar Work: The Non-Manual Labour Process, London:
Macmillan, 109-138. [SOCIOLOGY H-2 SMI]
Miller, H. (1995) The Management of Change in
Universities: Universities, State and Economy in
Australia, Canada and the United Kingdom, Buckingham:
Society for Research into Higher Education.
[UNIVERSITIES C-1 MIL]
Ovetz, R. (1996) =91Turning Resistance into Rebellion:
Student struggles and the global
entrepreneurialization of the universities=92 Capital
and Class, 58 (Spring): 113=96152.
Slaughter, S. and L. Leslie (1997) Academic Capitalism:
Politics, Policies, and the Entrepreneurial
University, Baltimore & London: John Hopkins
University Press. [UNIVERSITIES C-1 SLA]
Thompson, E.P. (1970) editor, Warwick University Ltd:
Industry, Management and the Universities,
Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Willmott, H. (1995) =91Managing the Academics:
Commodification and Control in the Development of
University Education in the U.K.=92, Human Relations,
vol. 48, no. 9, 993=971027.
Figure 1a and 1b. Cooperation/division of labour in
academic research: trends in average number of authors of
articles in seven journals. Note: Science and Nature each
publish several thousand articles annually. The averages
plotted in figure 1a are based on random samples of 60
articles for each year. They only cover the period since
1981, during which the necessary information has been
available on electronic indexes.
_______________________________
1This was perhaps less true in some sciences which have
always been more closely connected to industry,
especially =91defence=92.
2Of course the university system was financed through
general taxation, rather than by academics themselves.
Academics=92 teaching and admin duties could be compared to
the feudal tithe in that they in the time required for
them was set quite independently of what the academic did
in their remaining time, i.e., their research
=91performance=92.
3This is perhaps not strictly true since many people
become lecturers without first having been research
assistants. However, to become a lecturer one usually
needs both a Ph.D. and to demonstrate one=92s potential to
produce =91goods=92 publications; moreover, competition for
lecturing jobs is very fierce.
4This point is probably controversial. Of course marxism
can create problems for capital. In this sense it might
be useful to argue for a uniform reward for all
publications. This demand undermines research assessment
since it does not consider issues of =91quality=92,
refereeing and so on. But I think it is also true that
marxism as political economy, rather than critique of
political economy, can have some uses for capital. The
important point is that there is an antagonism between
doing research in order to critique capital and doing
research which will be quantified as part of one=92s work
within capital.
--Message-Boundary-16700
Content-type: text/plain; charset=ISO-8859-1
Content-transfer-encoding: Quoted-printable
Content-description: Text from file 'polemic.asc'
20
ALIENATION, CLASS AND ENCLOSURE IN UK UNIVERSITIES
David Harvie
February 1997
Thanks to Alfredo Saad-Filho, whose comments have
improved the argument and its presentation in this paper.
Introduction
The working conditions of many academics in UK
universities have deteriorated sharply over the past two
decades or so, even if `for many the academic labour
process remains in its core activities [of teaching,
research, scholarship, counselling and administration]
remarkably constant' in terms of the type or work (Miller
1991: 111). There have been dramatic and drastic changes
in higher education: university budgets, together with
funding in general, e.g., student grants, have been cut,
student numbers have increased and assessment of both
teaching and research has been introduced with a
vengence. There is no need to spell out the consequent
effect on academic workloads. Academics have been
squeezed by pressure from three sources. First, there is
an increased number of students: a system designed to
impart learning to a small elite, also providing an
element of pastoral care, is now struggling to adjust to
mass education. Second, related to the burgeoning student
population, and despite the employment of dedicated
administrators in many departments, is a growing burden
of administration. Third, there is research, the focus of
this Polemic.
My argument in a nutshell is that academic researchers in
U.K. universities are in the midst of a revolution, which
is somewhat akin to the transition from feudalism to
capitalism. If successfully completed, this revolution
will have disastrous consequences for the majority of
research academics' freedom and job security. As part of
this revolution we are seeing a number of related
processes:
the reduction of essentially unmeasureable research use-
values to quantifiable `research value';
primitive accumulation and enclosure of academic
`commons';
the emergence of two classes of academic, a research
capitalist class and a research proletariat, with the
class of research capitalists starting to challenge
heads of department (`lords of the manor') in terms of
the economic and political power they wield within
higher education.
Related to these processes are increasing specialisation
and division of academic labour.
Higher education and capital; universities as
intellectual commons
The integration of higher education into the capitalist
economy has long been recognised by Marxists. Theorists
of the `social factory' such as Mario Tronti argued that,
far from being in some sense outside of capitalist social
relations, schools and universities' role as shapers of
young workers, as (re)creators of labour-power, made them
central to the process of value- and surplus value-
creation. There is also a long history of links between
business and universities, with an equally long history
of people organising struggles against these links and
the subsumption of the interests of both university
students and staff to those of capital accumulation. An
early example of this is the subject of Warwick
University Ltd (Thompson 1970); more recent ones, in the
Canadian and US contexts, respectively, are discussed in
Buckbinder and Newson (1988) and Ovetz (1996).
Interesting in this context is the recent explicit
recognition by the present government that much education
policy, and in particular, government stipulations on
curricula in schools and course content in higher and
further education, will be guided by the expressed needs
of `business'. Recently, some so-called `failing' schools
in the US and the UK have even been taken over by the
corporate sector. [ref. the economist] The past couple of
decades have seen closer links between universities and
private sector companies as academics have sought money
to make up for falling state funding. Slaughter and
Leslie define `institutional and professorial market or
market-like efforts to secure external moneys' as
`academic capitalism', in their book of the same title
(1997: 8). In this Polemic, however, this term conveys a
different meaning.
A number of other changes and trends have been identified
and theorised. Several authors, for example, have
examined the rise of managerialism in higher education
(refs) and the proletarianisation of academics (refs).
Wilmott (1995) argues that there have been major
developments in the past 10 or so years which have
`significantly eroded the protection from pressures to
render [academics'] work more commensurable with the
commodity form of value' (p. 995)
Miller (1995) discusses in detail the changes in
universities in terms of a number of agencies and
relationships. These include `the state and universities'
and `the economy and universities' and `university
management and academics'. At each `level' there are
forces acting to pressurise academics. I have no argument
with Miller's account of these shifts and forces;
however, they tell only part of the story. The dynamic
forces described by Miller are all external to academics:
in addition, there are forces which are internal to the
body of academics. Within universities themselves
`management' (or `the university') is counterposed to
`academics'. `Managment' may well include many (mostly
senior) academics: these individuals gain management
status through appointment or election to a governing
body (e.g., senate or council) or position (e.g., head of
department). Academics, as academics, though Miller is
well aware that different individuals and groups are
being affected in different ways by current changes, are
seen as a universal body.
However, despite this integration of education
institutions within the capitalist economy, the
relationship until recently has largely been external. By
this I mean simply that the internal organisation of
universities, and other research institutions, has not
been capitalistic. By and large, they have not been
realms within which anything like the law of value has
operated. Despite its `ivory tower' moniker, H.E. has not
been any bastion of `liberty, equality and solidarity',
though many academics have enjoyed far better conditions
than many other workers. Rather, universities have
historically been organised along lines which in some
ways have been far more akin to feudalism and/or an
artisan-centred economy.
Consider the position of the British university academic
two decades ago, say. This person employed as a Lecturer
or Senior Lecturer enjoyed almost complete job security.
In return, this academic was required to devote a fairly
smallish proportion of their time to teaching and
administrative duties. A level of research activity was
also expected, depending upon the particular institution,
but monitoring of this was minimal: the contracted
obligation was to engage in reasearch or other `scholarly
activity', rather than to produce a research output.
Although research output of high quantity and quality
would almost certainly be rewarded financially through
promotion, to a Readership or Chair, say, and in terms of
academic prestige, even a university lecturer who
published nothing could expect to enjoy a high and, for
the most part, rising income, which placed them amongst
Britain's highest earners, on a par with senior civil
servants and top police officers.
This situation of material security allowed research
activity to be organised in a particular way. In some
respects academics were akin to artisans, in others
perhaps to serfs. Most worked alone and the products of
their labour _ research _ formed a collection of use-
values.1 Academics did research because they wanted to
and, with few external pressures, published only if they
thought they had some ideas or results worth publishing.
Within this system, the requirements for researh _
library facilities, an office, an intellectually
stimulating environment and, probably most importantly,
time _ were available to all academics who wished to make
use of them: for employed academics these resources were
intellectual commons; the `tithe' that they paid was the
set proportion of their time which they had to devote to
teaching and administrative duties.2 For students, though
not the focus of this Polemic, the combination of less
pressured academics, well-stocked libraries, the grant
system and few graduation employment worries meant that
for them too, universities were intellectual commons.
Within this system, academics were usually answerable to
their heads of department. With nearly all academics
enjoying tenure, the departmental head's position was
more akin to that of the feudal lord: s/he could try and
discipline the `lazy' lecturer, using moral pressure or a
few extra administrative or teaching duties, but sacking
them was usually not an option. Nevertheless, a common
opinion is that heads of department were much more
powerful, and less accountable, in the past, and in some
cases had the power to destroy someone's career. From the
lecturer's perspective, they were of course, unlike the
feudal serf, free to move if they chose. But, with fewer
pressures to constantly improve research performance, and
seek promotion, there was simply less reason to do so.
At a mostly subjective level `good' research was
distinguished from `bad'; there were generally-accepted
notions of `good' journals, departments and individuals,
etc., but these things were not quantified, nor as
mentioned above was there a close correlation between
research quantity and `quality' and material reward.
Moreover, academics passed through a period of
apprenticeship, completing a Ph.D. or some other research
project, under the guidance of an established academic,
the `Master', a point made in passing by Marglin (1974).
An important characteristic of this apprentice system was
that the project was the student's own _ a prospective
D.Phil. candidate would usually write their own proposal,
obtain their own funding from an H.E. institution or
funding body, and choose (or negotiate) their own
supervisor(s). Once the apprenticeship was satisfactorily
completed, young academics could fairly easily move into
a lecturing position, gaining control of sufficient
resources-the researcher's `commons': sufficient free
time, money, use of a library and possibly a computer-to
continue their own research. Thus the apprentice became
journeyman.
Neoliberalism and the imposition of the law of value in
H.E.
The attempt to impose the law of value in academia can be
seen as being part of the economy-wide and global project
of neo-liberalism. It is fundamentally concerned with
strengthening the link between money and work, in this
case research work. In academia, this project has several
elements. Perhaps the most fundamental is the
quantification or valorisation of research, through which
researchers are also becoming increasingly alienated from
the product of their labour. If there is to be a strong
link between money and work in universities then it must
be possible to quantify academic research work. In the
UK, this is happening through research selectivity
exercises, the universal (across all disciplines), four-
yearly (at present) Research Assessment Exercise (RAE).
Standards of measurement vary. In some disciplines
authorship of books is the principal unit. In others,
such as economics, refereed journal articles are
preferred, with journals ranked such that a publication
in one may be `worth' much more than a publication in
another. The point is that research output is no longer
simply a use-value; it now has RAE-value which, as I go
to argue, has an similar purpose within academia to
exchange-value or value, in the normal Marxist sense, in
the wider economy. Standardisation and method of
measurement are still incompletely worked out: the
Chairman and Deputy Chairman of the Business and
Management RAE Panel for the 1996 Exercise discuss some
of these issues in an article in Cooper and Otley (1998).
Miller (1995) discusses some of the external changes to
funding and so on which have been driving the process.
>From 1974 block grants from central government fell from
making up 77% of total university income to only 55% in
1987. In 1986 the basis for funding changed: funding for
research is now dependent upon a department's research
reputation and the amount of awards it has been granted
from independent research grant-awarding bodies. In 1986,
the year of the first research assessment exercise, the
proportion of research funds allocated on its basics was
10%. This rose to 30% in 1989 and 100% in 1992 (Miller
1995: 16 and 144). Moreover, the 1991 White Paper Higher
Education: A New Framework and subsequent 1992 Act
provisioned increased competition and selectivity in
research funding (Miller 1995: 17-18).
Linked to the funding question is that of labour
contracts. The Education Reform Act of 1988 `appointed
comminssioners to ensure that university statutes make
provision for the dismissal of staff on the grounds of
redundancy - that is, when the institution ceases to
carry on an activity, teaching or research, for which a
person was appointed' (Miller 1995: 17). And Miller
suggests the national pay dispute of 1988-9, with its
imposed settlement of May 1989, was significant in that
it paved the way for both performance-related pay and
market-related pay at the discretion of local university
management (Miller 1995: 134). In 1993, at Aston
University, for example, control of use of discretionary
money passed to departments with the development of the
`trading company model', which designated academic,
administrative and service-providing departments as cost
centres (Miller 1995: 145-147).
There are two points which should be noted about research
and its RAE-value. Firstly, (RAE-)valorisation is not
something which occurs after the research has been
produced. Rather, RAE-valorisation has become an organic
part of the production process itself. Research is
produced for the RAE, research projects and the papers
they will most likely yield are conceived, planned and
executed always with at least one eye on the next RAE.
Given the rewards and costs involved, this is almost
inevitable.
Secondly, the RAE-value of research is not determined by
the actual, or concrete, research labour time (quantity
of work) taken to produce it. Instead the RAE-value of a
journal article, say, is determined by some notion of
`socially necessary' research labour time, how long it
would take for the `average' academic to produce. These
norms here are as yet incompletely worked out, which is
not surprising given that there have been only four
research selectivity/assessment exercises to date (in
1986, 1989, 1992 and 1996) and given the difficulties
from the assossors' point of view. (For example, the
`research cycle' is uneven: long years without
publications may lead to a large number of closely
related papers.) In 1996, `economists', i.e., those
researchers working in economics departments or assessed
by a/the panel of economists, were judged by their four
`best' journal articles over the previous four years.
Thus, we can interpret this as meaning that if one wants
to be considered a `good' economist, one must publish (at
least) one article, in a `good' journal, every year; or
that, the socially necessary research labour time for the
production of a `good' article is tending towards one
year. Of course, the four-yearly assessment is rather
unwieldy, generating both a flurry of `transfer activity'
(`top' academics moving to departments wishing to improve
their rating and willing to pay) prior to the research
submission deadline and a vast workload for the
assessors. According to the more informed rumours,
research selectivity therefore appears to be moving in
the direction towards continuous assessment. Presumably
the ideal scenario (from the assessors' perspective)
would be one in which researchers and their research are
assessed at the time of publication.
At present, RAE results are published in the form of a
rating, ranging from `5*' for the most research-
productive departments, down to `1'. More disaggregated
figures, rating individual research groups within a
department are also made available, to that department.
It is thus possible to rate individual academics in the
same way. As a result of therefore of this process of RAE-
valorisation it is increasingly possible to measure the
work of a labour economist, say, against that of a growth-
cycle theorist, or possibly even an astrophysicist or a
specialist in renaissance Italian literature (or
whatever).
Research selectivity, and the process I am describing as
RAE-valorisation, is having or is likely to have a number
of effects.
1. Perfomance-related pay. Of course, to some extent,
academics' pay is already dependent upon their individual
research performance. Promotion (which carries enhance
pay, of course) depends upon an academic's research
record to a far greater extent than their ability in
either of their other two `core' activities of teaching
and administration. The same can be said of the award of
discretionary points in the salary scale. With the RAE
inducing far more `transfer activity' between academic
departments it is likely we will see a closer link
between research performance and remuneration. Put
simply, many departments in search of a high RAE research
rating are willing to offer higher salaries to attract
academics with impressive CVs; in turn these same
academics' current employers must be prepared to offer
them comparative rewards in order to keep them.
One current proposals is the introduction of profit
related pay schemes which would first require academics
to accept a notional pay cut. The removed slice would go
into a `profit pool', which would then be redistributed.
Proponents argue the end result would be increased pay,
but this would be dependant upon the university achieving
a `surplus'. This proposal would also involve a change in
contracts which would undermine national collective
bargaining. The introduction of differentials between
universities would also pave the way for wage
differentials within universities. (see AUT Update no.
35)
2. Influence of the type of research done. Harley and Lee
(1998) suggest the RAE, in economics at least, is forcing
researchers towards the orthodox, neoclassical paradigm.
Their argument is simply that the orthodox journals are
more prestigious and therefore articles published in
those journals are `worth more' than those published in
non-mainstream alternatives. They present evidence to
show that many economics departments actively encourage
applicants with mainstream-journal publications when they
have job vacancies. Academic economists with insecure job
tenure are thus under pressure to do research within the
orthodoxy. More generally, the pressure on all academics,
whatever their discipline, to produce research output, as
opposed to simply being engaged in research, must mean
there is an incentive to undertake `safe' research
projects, that is, those which are more likely to yield
publishable, if not Earth-shattering, results. Moreover,
with assessement every four years, the incentive must be
to not to engage in lengthy research projects. You wonder
what would have become of the British mathematician
Andrew Wiles, based at Princeton University, who in 1994
solved the 350 year old Fermat's Last Theorem, a
fantastic achievement. Wiles spent seven years working on
the problem, with no certainty of success, and during
that time did little other research. Or of Sraffa
3. Alienation. There are several aspects to alienation.
With research selectivity academics are under pressure to
maximise the RAE-value of their research. At the limit,
this will be the only consideration when submitting and
publishing work. In all other respects the destination of
their research product will be a matter of indifference:
the researcher exchanges their product for RAE-value and
through this mechanism of exchange becomes alienated from
this product. At editors of Capital and Class, we have
certainly noticed a trend in this direction over the past
few years. Where once Capital and Class would have been
first-choice, many authors are more likely to initially
submit articles to `higher-ranking' journals _ usually
journals which reach a far smaller socialist/communist
readership. Of course, changes in an author's `target'
journal will probably imply changes in their paper's
content, too. Socialist/communist research loses out.
Again, at the limit, reseach done purely to generate RAE-
value does not satisfy the human need to create
(understanding and knowledge in the case of academics).
Such research work becomes a chore imposed by others and
is undertaken merely to satisfy needs external to the
activity itself.
Research capitalists and proletarians; publications as
capital; the accumulation of academic capital;
enclosures and primitive accumulation
Alienation in a stricter sense involves not only
alienating one's product but one's labour-power as well _
the selling of one's labour-power. Here both labour-power
and the product of the resulting labour belong to the
employer. If we equate `ownership' with named authorship
of research papers, it is clear this already happens in
academia, whenever a research `assistant' or `fellow' is
employed.
What matters in academia are publications. What matters
most are single- or first-author articles in a `good'
refereed journal, published recently such that they
`count' towards the next RAE. Having (`owning') such
publications provides one with greater access to the
resources necessary to pursue further research, research
`means of production', which are made available through
obtaining an academic job and/or research grant. The
research worker, as a rule, `possesses' few such
publications and therefore has an extremely limited
access to these `means of production'. The research
worker, in short, owns nothing but their ability to do
research and is therefore forced to seek employment as a
research assistant.3 On the other hand, the `research
capitalist' is someone with many publications to their
name. Such publications mean that this person is not only
likely to be able to obtain a senior academic job, they
are also likely to be successful in applications for
larger research grants. Large research grants allow one
or more research assistants (or research fellows) to be
employed. The crucial point here is that these
researchers are working on someone else's project. Of
course research managers do not have complete control
over the production process nor can they appropriate all
that is produced, but again this is to miss the point: in
any work-place, the employer's control of the work
process and the product is limited to a greater or less
extent and is subject to struggle. Directors of research
projects are named authors on resulting papers.
(Arrangements concerning authorship vary, of course. In
some projects the research assistants will be first-
author; in others their name will appear only in the
acknowledgements.) In effect research directors are
setting in motion research labour-power. It is the
`ownership' (authorship) of publications which confers
this power on them and the result, if the project(s) is
successful, is the `accumulation' of more RAE-value
(publications). The situation for the research assistant
at the end of a research project varies. Sometimes, they
will have gained authorship of a sufficient number of
publications, as part of the project, to be a position to
obtain a lecturing job, say, which allows them greater
freedom, though this might be only as a result of
struggling to pursue their own projects at the same time
as their research assistant research. In other cases, the
research project will end leaving them in the same
position as at the beginning _ owning insufficient
publications to do anything but obtain another research
assistant position.
It is increasingly common for some academics to
simultaneously be director of several projects. Such an
individual may well approach the extreme of a `pure'
research capitalist. This person is able to employ a
large number of research workers, who not only do the
bulk of the research work, but whose job also includes
writing new research proposals, under the direction of
the research capitalist, to fund the next project and
most likely to secure their own future employment. In
such a way the research capitalist is able to accumulate
a vast number of publications and control huge resources.
With their extensive CV this person is likely to gain
widespread authority within their discipline, through
editorship of key journals or positions on funding
councils, say and is thus able to have disproportionate
influence over its future direction. With their control
of significant monetary resources, they will wield
considerable power within their own department and
university, and therefore challenging the established
hierarchy of heads of departments, deans and so on. (Of
course, research capitalists may be heads of department,
but this doesn't affect the argument _ some feudal lords
became successful capitalists.)
If their secure income, limited teaching and
administrative committments and rich library resources
were the academic-of-old's intellectual commons, then the
current ongoing process in UK HE is one of enclosures and
primitive accumulation. This process is uneven, of
course. At the most basic level of material security, one
third of UK academics are now employed on fixed-term
contracts (AUT ??). In a large number of departments,
even for those academics with tenure, access to the
`intellectual commons' is being squeezed, by the pincers
of rising student numbers and falling budgets for
library, computing, conference, etc. facilities. The
typical academic in such a department, if they wish to
engage in a serious research project, is likely to be
forced to depend upon a series of discretionary grants in
order to `buy out' teaching, purchase a adequate
computer, etc. In those `top' departments with better
`permanent' research facilities, the long-term
maintenence of these facilities is likely to depend upon
`good' collective research performance and researchers in
these departments will be under considerable pressure
(both formal and informal) to `pull their weight'.
Specialization and division of labour
A by-product of this research-bourgeois revolution is to
accelerate the process of specialisation and division of
research labour. This is further contributing to academic
alienation, on at least two levels.
First, academic disciplines (and sub-disciplines and so
on) are becoming more specialised and there is an
exponential growth in new specialisms. With this growth
it becomes more difficult for any single researcher,
struggling to keep up with advances in their own and
related specialisms, to step back to view their work in a
broader perspective. The new pressures to produce `good',
i.e., publishable, research at the `cutting edges' mean
practicing researchers have even less time in which to
pursue the goal of wider intellectual understanding. In
effect researcher workers are becoming increasingly
alienated from society's body of knowledge, which they
have helped produce and continue to expand. And as
researchers become alienated from societal knowledge,
this leaves others with more political and economic power
free to interpret and therefore appropriate for their own
ends this knowledge.
Second, at the level of individual research projects, an
increasing proportion of research is collaborative,
whether or not such research is done under the direction
of a research capitalist or is more self-managed. These
research groups range in size from just a couple of
people to teams of perhaps one or two dozen people
(common in applied physical science). In such projects,
each team member specializes in a different aspect of the
research, and may have limited or no involvement in the
other aspects. As a result, they may not fully understand
the final results. It now seems common for the presenter
of a (multi-authored) paper in an applied economics
seminar, say, to prohibit questions on the econometrics
on the grounds that this was carried out by (one of)
their co-author(s) and they do not really understand it!
Also common is the applied econometrician or statistician
who analyses data sets with only a very hazy
understanding of either the conditions under which the
data was collected or the theoretical framework driving
the quantitative questions they are supposed to be
answering. In these cases it must be said that these
researchers have become alienated from the knowledge they
are producing. With a goal of `increased productivity'
such a division of labour may be necessary, but with
proficiency in any one element of a research project's
work requiring years of practice, some degree of such
alienation is perhaps inevitable.
This phenomenon has obvious implications, which I do not
need to spell out here, for the balance of power between
employed research worker, on the one hand, and the
research project director (i.e., the research
capitalist), on the other.
The process of primitive accumulation and capitalist
revolution I am attempting to describe has reached
different stages in different academic disciplines.
Broadly speaking, at the risk of being charged with
technological determinism, this appears to depend upon
the extent of the material needs of research in that
discipline. Another factor is the degree to which
`outputs' can be separated from `inputs'. In arts
subjects and many social sciences research and production
are very personal; output is inseparable from (personal)
input. The process is most advanced in the physical
sciences, in which research activity demands a large
amount of expensive equipment. It is common for research
in subjects like astrophysics and chemistry to be carried
out by teams of a dozen or more people, under the
direction of a single senior researcher. It seems to be
least advanced in the arts where, on the whole, very
little equipment is required to do research. The social
sciences and humanities lie somewhere in-between.
Collaborative research does not necessarily mean research
undertaken by research workers directed by a research
capitalist; nor does it necessarily that the members of a
research team will be alienated from the research
`product'. It may instead indicate greater cooperation
amongst free producers. However, the extent to which
collaborative research has become more widespread over
the past few decades, across a range of disciplines is
interesting and suggests my thesis cannot be immediately
rejected. The figures plots the mean number of authors
per article published by seven differents journals,
including Capital and Class, over the past four decades.
In all cases there is a clear trend towards more
collaborative work.
FIGURES 1A AND 1B HERE
The poverty of opposition
The process I have been describing is marked by the
limited extent of most critiques and opposition. The
fundamental purpose of the process is to control academic
workers through the imposition of a strong link between
money and work. The process also influences the nature
and content of academic research. There is a possibility
that, eventually, in order to get the rewards (RAE-value,
funding, etc.) all problems to be tackled must be
sanctioned as such by the `establishment'_well-
established researchers, funding agencies, Parliament,
corporations. Academics end up being cajoled into solving
problems for the establishment_capital's problems! This
is already very clear in those fields more closely
affected by military research. RAE-valorisation should be
opposed in its totality.
Unfortunately most opposition to date seems to have
focused on attempting to modify the way in which research
assessment is implemented. One tendency is to argue for
different scales on which to judge and measure differing
research output. Another is concerned with the effect on
non-orthodox research within the social sciences, for
example. This tendency is keen to emphasise that Marxist
or radical research shouldn't be discriminated against.
But by doing so, the point that this research is still
being reduced to pure RAE-value and that work is still
being imposed is implicitly conceded: Marxism thereby
becomes a potentially `profitable' niche market.4
Perhaps the idea of a research strike, along the lines of
the Art Strike 1990-1993, proposed by the PRAXIS group in
1985 is worth debating. For the art strike, the
propaganda and discussion in the period leading up to its
proposed start were of more importance than the strike
itself, which was probably never a serious proposition.
(See Home 1989 and Here and Now 1990).
Conclusion _ social antagonism and class in academia
My argument perhaps becomes still clearer if we
understand class, not as a defined group of people, but
rather as being based primarily on the antagonism in the
way human social practice is organised. Although `the
polar nature of the antagonism is reflected in a
polarisation of the two classes, the antagonism is prior
to, not subsequent to, the classses: classes are
constituted through the antagonism' (Holloway 1998:
183-4). Holloway suggests social antagonism
is a conflict between creative social practice and
its negation, or, in other words, between humanity
and its negation, between the transcending of limits
(creation) and the imposition of limits
(definition). The conflict does not take place after
subordination has been established, after the
fetishised forms of social relations have been
constituted: rather it is a conflict about the
subordination of social practice, about the
fetishisation of social relations (1998: 183).
Research, the pursuit of knowledge and understanding, in
any field you care to think of, is creative human
activity. For many `professional' thinkers there is (or
was) no real distinction between work and leisure.
Although in the past there have been barriers between
`disciplines', these were far less clear cut than they
were today. Such creativity is being defined to death.
Within academic research there seem to be limits
whichever way you turn: what to read, how to think, how
to write, how many words to write, who to cite (creative
work turned against creators), where to publish and so on
and so on and now, with `research assessment', how many
articles to publish. Of course, there are always people
attempting to overcome these limits. There are always
people attempting to transcend discipline barriers,
despite the huge costs often involved, in terms of
reading new literatures, putting one's position within
one's `own' discipline at risk, and so on. Moreover, many
transcending `seminal' papers, which cut across
`(sub)disciplines' end up imposing limits as a new
`(sub)discipline'.
This antagonism in academia, between creativity and its
limitation, is not especially new. What is new is the
power which `research assessment' promises/threatens to
measure and define. In turn measurement and definition
offers capital greater opportunities to limit and control
intellectual creativity within universities through
enclosure of `intellectual commons'. Researchers thus
become alienated from their creative output. What is also
new is the extent to which `research assessment', and its
related research-funding arrangements, offers a small
minority of academics the opportunity to participate
directly in and benefit from the exploitation and
appropriation of the research work, the creativity, of
others, the majority of us. It is in this way that
antagonism in academia is now constituting two new
classes within academia.
References
AUT (1996) Update, no. 35, 3 June, London: AUT.
Harley, S. and F.S. Lee (1997) `Research Selectivity,
Managerialism, and the Academic Labour Process: The
Future of Nonmainstream Economics in U.K.
Universities', Human Relations, vol.50, no. 11, 1426-
1460.
Here and Now (1990) `Art/Anti-Art Supplement' to issue
10.
Holloway, J. (1998) `Dignity's Revolt', in J. Holloway
and Elo=A1na Pel=A0ez (eds) Zapatista! Reinventing
Revolution in Mexico, London and Sterling, VA: Pluto
Press, 159-198.
Home, S. (1989) editor Art Strike Handbook, London.
Lee, F.S. and S. Harley (1998) `Economics Divided: The
Limitations of Peer Review in a Paradigm-Bound Social
Science', Capital and Class, 66 (Autumn), pages.
Marglin, S. (1974) `What do bosses do? The Origins and
Functions of Hierarchy in Capitalist Production'
Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 6, Summer.
Also in Gorz, A., editor, The Division of Labour: The
Labour Process and Class Struggle in Modern
Capitalism. Brighton: Harvester, 1976.
Miller, H. (1991) `Academics and their Labour Process' in
C. Smith, D. Knights and H. Willmott (eds.) White-
Collar Work: The Non-Manual Labour Process, London:
Macmillan, 109-138. [SOCIOLOGY H-2 SMI]
Miller, H. (1995) The Management of Change in
Universities: Universities, State and Economy in
Australia, Canada and the United Kingdom, Buckingham:
Society for Research into Higher Education.
[UNIVERSITIES C-1 MIL]
Ovetz, R. (1996) `Turning Resistance into Rebellion:
Student struggles and the global
entrepreneurialization of the universities' Capital
and Class, 58 (Spring): 113-152.
Slaughter, S. and L. Leslie (1997) Academic Capitalism:
Politics, Policies, and the Entrepreneurial
University, Baltimore & London: John Hopkins
University Press. [UNIVERSITIES C-1 SLA]
Thompson, E.P. (1970) editor, Warwick University Ltd:
Industry, Management and the Universities,
Harmondsworth: Penguin.
Willmott, H. (1995) `Managing the Academics:
Commodification and Control in the Development of
University Education in the U.K.', Human Relations,
vol. 48, no. 9, 993_1027.
Figure 1a and 1b. Cooperation/division of labour in
academic research: trends in average number of authors of
articles in seven journals. Note: Science and Nature each
publish several thousand articles annually. The averages
plotted in figure 1a are based on random samples of 60
articles for each year. They only cover the period since
1981, during which the necessary information has been
available on electronic indexes.
_______________________________
1This was perhaps less true in some sciences which have
always been more closely connected to industry,
especially `defence'.
2Of course the university system was financed through
general taxation, rather than by academics themselves.
Academics' teaching and admin duties could be compared to
the feudal tithe in that they in the time required for
them was set quite independently of what the academic did
in their remaining time, i.e., their research
`performance'.
3This is perhaps not strictly true since many people
become lecturers without first having been research
assistants. However, to become a lecturer one usually
needs both a Ph.D. and to demonstrate one's potential to
produce `goods' publications; moreover, competition for
lecturing jobs is very fierce.
4This point is probably controversial. Of course marxism
can create problems for capital. In this sense it might
be useful to argue for a uniform reward for all
publications. This demand undermines research assessment
since it does not consider issues of `quality',
refereeing and so on. But I think it is also true that
marxism as political economy, rather than critique of
political economy, can have some uses for capital. The
important point is that there is an antagonism between
doing research in order to critique capital and doing
research which will be quantified as part of one's work
within capital.
--Message-Boundary-16700--
Display software:
ArchTracker © Malgosia Askanas, 2000-2005